This piece attempts to look at three cases of
corruption from a set of countries located in various points of the spectrum
that is public corruption. In consideration are Kenya, USA and Denmark. This is
a choice that was curated keeping in mind the comparative possibilities that
these countries offer in terms of syndromes of corruption, namely, Official
Moguls and Influential Markets.
Rushabh Menon in his article on Kenya’s Moi regime
(1978-2002) outlines three instances of the instance of Official Mogul, by
which the dictator stifled political and economic dissent and allowed free
access to Kenya’s natural resources and economy to his inner circle. These
surreptitious activities were usually masked by cleverly executed international
and private sector deals with complicated currency exchange. Kenya presents
with a set of features endemic to the developing world in the face of
Structural Readjustment and Neo- liberal market economies. The fact that this
scandal was started to coincide with the liberalization of the market in 1991
is a relevant point here. Rushabh also, very promptly points out that the
Bofors scandal in India under Rajiv Gandhi is an analogous case study here.
USA, a country seen as slightly less corrupt than at
least Kenya, is a case study worthy of the exercise Vishali Sairam has
attempted. She highlights the nexus between the global market, politicians and
communities through Super- PACs. Influential markets are able to dictate
political policy and political agenda, and even the highest offices of the
government often seek advice from powerful private players. This becomes ever
more of a problem when politicians trade policy favours in return for support
in legislation or funding for a campaign. Vishali rightfully points at the
illusion that the American public has regarding the Republican Party front
runner Donald Trump that “he funds his own campaign and hence ‘cannot be
bought’”. Setting aside factual inaccuracies in Trump’s claim, one really needs
to see that if Trump cannot be influenced by potential donors, there is a
distinct possibility that Trump can set and further his own agenda, which might
not turn out to be in the best interests of the American public, or even, the
world.
On the other end of the spectrum is Denmark, enjoying
Transparency International’s first spot for three continuous years now.
However, Anand Sreekumar rightfully questions the very criteria of this
measurement and argues that mere transparency and politeness from public
officials cannot be concluded as less corruption. He sees influential markets
in action here, with private interests meddling with political activity, in
terms of political donations, much similar to the USA. What becomes a problem
here is the fact that these donations and money sources are often not made
public knowledge and political parties are not held accountable for these. What
he also points at is that it is such minor details that count in accounting for
public office and the fact that Denmark is universally acknowledged as the
least corrupt country makes it difficult to initiate changes.
These three case studies have presented to us the
varying faces and forms that corruption takes- from outright violation of human
rights to shady gray areas of legality, to an altogether blatant legal
opaqueness, countries occupying different locations in the spectrum of
corruption have each to offer an
analysis of the character of institutional corruption itself.
No comments:
Post a Comment